Policy Debate:
Does an increase in the minimum wage result in a higher unemployment rate?
Issues and Background
The minimum wage does not prevent everyone from getting any job.
But the minimum wage does make it more difficult for those who already
have a hard time getting a job - the least skilled - to begin or continue
a career. Passing a law that forces people to earn a minimum amount
in order to work seems a cruel policy in an already cruel world?
~Donald
R. Deere
Our findings suggest that the efficiency aspects of a modest rise
in the minimum wage are overstated.... [W]e find no evidence for a large
negative employment effect of higher minimum wages. Even in the earlier
literature, however, the magnitude of the predicted employment losses
from a much higher minimum wage would be small: the evidence at hand
is relevant only for a moderate range of minimum wages, such as those
that prevailed in the U.S. labor market during the past few decades.
Within this range, however, there is little reason to believe that increases
in the minimum wage will generate large employment losses.
~David Card and Alan B. Krueger, Myth and Measurement: The New Economics
of the Minimum Wage, (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1995, p.
393).
Minimum wage laws in the U.S. were first introduced during the 1930s
in response to the Great Depression. This period was characterized by
falling output, falling prices, and falling employment. The National Industrial
Recovery Act (NIRA) of 1933 attempted to stop this downward spiral by
encouraging the formation of trade association agreements that established
price floors and minimum wages. This was the first national attempt to
introduce minimum wages in major industries. Those firms that participated in the trade association agreements were able
to display a "blue eagle" logo in their establishments. In 1935,
the U.S. Supreme Court ruled that the NIRA was unconstitutional, and these
initial minimum wage agreements were terminated.
In 1938, the Fair Labor Standards Act (FLSA) established a national minimum
wage of $0.25 an hour. (This act also established restrictions on child
labor and required that overtime pay be provided for hours of work in
excess of 40 hours per week.) This Act initially only applied to a relatively
small share of the labor force, but has been revised over time so that
it now applies to approximately 90% of all nonsupervisory workers.
Introductory economics textbooks usually first introduce the minimum
wage as an application of demand and supply analysis. This initial discussion
is usually based on the following assumptions:
- the labor market is perfectly competitive,
- the minimum wage covers all workers, and
- worker productivity is unaffected by the wage rate.
Under these assumptions, the effect of the minimum wage is quite straightforward:
the introduction of a minimum wage results in unemployment in those labor
markets in which the equilibrium wage rate is below the minimum wage.
This is illustrated in the diagram below:

In the labor market illustrated above, the equilibrium wage
would be w* and the equilibrium level of employment would be L* in the
absence of a minimum wage. When a minimum wage of wmin is introduced,
however, the level of employment falls to LD. Notice that the
quantity of labor demanded exceeds the quantity of labor supplied at this
minimum wage. A total of LS - LD unemployed
workers will be created by the introduction of this minimum wage.
While minimum wage increases generally receive substantial
public support, economists have generally relied on the above analysis
to argue that such legislation will result in an increase in the unemployment
rate in low-wage labor markets. In recent years, however, a series of
studies by David Card, Alan B. Krueger, Lawrence F. Katz, and others have
suggested that small to moderate increases in the minimum wage will have
no adverse effects on unemployment (and may even lead to reduced unemployment).
There are a number of theoretical models that can explain such results.
Among these are:
- monopsony models, and
- efficiency wage models.
In a monopsony labor market, there is a single employer of workers. This
employer faces an upward sloping labor supply curve. Because the cost
of hiring an extra worker (the marginal factor cost) exceeds the wage
rate, a monopsony firm will hire fewer workers than would be hired in
a perfectly competitive labor market. This is illustrated in the diagram
below.

As the diagram above indicates, a profit-maximizing monopsonist
will hire an optimal quantity of labor at the point at which the firm's
marginal revenue product (MRP = the additional revenue associated with
the use of an additional unit of labor) equals the firm's marginal factor
cost (MFC = the additional cost associated with the use of an additional
unit of labor). In this case, the optimal level of employment occurs at
Lm. When this firm hires Lm workers, the labor supply
curve indicates that it must pay a wage equal to wm.
If a minimum wage is introduced into this labor market,
the labor supply curve effectively becomes horizontal at this wage up
to the point at which the minimum wage intersects the supply curve. This
is illustrated in the diagram below. The thicker red line represents the
labor supply curve in the presence of a minimum wage equal to wmin.
Because the wage is constant in this portion of the labor supply curve,
the marginal factor cost is constant and equal to the minimum wage in
this range. Once the labor supply curve starts rising again, the marginal
factor cost once again is above the wage (in the diagram below, this occurs
once the level of employment exceeds Lmin).

If a minimum wage equal to wmin is introduced
into this market, the optimal level of employment for the monopsony firm
will occur at Lmin (since MRP = MFC at this point). Thus, it
is possible that the introduction of a minimum wage will result in both
higher wages and a higher level of employment. If the minimum wage is
set anywhere between wm and w', employment will increase in
a monopsony labor market. A minimum wage equal to w' will result in the
same level of employment as in the monopsony outcome (although with a
higher wage). Employment will fall if the minimum wage is set above w'
in this labor market.
The efficiency wage model suggests that firms that pay workers
a wage above the equilibrium wage will find that the higher pay results
in more productive workers. The higher pay results in less labor force
turnover, lower training costs, and better motivated workers. If the increase
in labor productivity is sufficiently large, an increase in the minimum
wage need not reduce employment.
Much of the controversy surrounds a study conducted by David Card and
Alan Krueger. In this study, Card and Krueger conducted a phone survey
of 410 fast-food restaurants on both sides of the border between Pennsylvania
and New Jersey prior to and after an increase in the state minimum wage
in New Jersey. They found that employment increased by more in New Jersey
in response to the higher minimum wage in this state.
Because of concerns about the Card and Krueger data, the Employment Policies
Institute examined payroll records for 71 fast-food restaurants and found
significant discrepancies between the Card and Krueger data and payroll
records for these firms. They found significantly different results when
their revised data was used for estimation purposes. Critics of the EPI
study argue that the selection process used to generate the Employment
Policies Institute sample appears not to be random (all Pennsylvania observations
are Burger King restaurants owned by a single franchise owner).
Those who believe that increases in the minimum wage will not adversely
affect employment argue that, even if there are some problems with the
data used by Card and Krueger in their study of fast-food restaurants
in New Jersey and Pennsylvania, there is a growing empirical literature
that provides quite similar results. Card and Krueger
present an extensive collection of such studies in Myth and Measurement
(1995).
An issue related to that of a minimum wage is a growing movement for
a "living wage." Living wage proposals suggest that the existing
minimum wage is too low to allow families to exceed the poverty level.
Advocates of this view support "living wage ordinances" that
require the local government to only accept contracts from firms (or,
in some cities, provide assistance to firms) that pay their workers a
wage that is high enough to place the worker above the poverty line. Baltimore
was the first city to adopt such an ordinance in 1994. Under Baltimore's
"living wage" requirement, firms must pay a worker an hourly
wage that will allow a full-time worker to receive an annual income greater
than or equal to the poverty level for a family of three.
One of the reasons why the minimum wage is so often the focus of political
debate is that it is set at a specific nominal value and is not indexed
to inflation. Thus, as inflation occurs, the real value of the minimum
wage declines until Congress decides to pass new legislation. (The highest
real value of the minimum wage was reached in 1968.) Because of this,
it is likely that the debate over the effects of the minimum wage will
continue to remain a significant source of political and economic debate.
Primary Resources and Data
Anti-Minimum Wage Increase
Paul Kersey, "A Minimum-Wage Hike Wouldn't Add Up"
A Minimum-Wage Hike Wouldn't Add Up
In this July 22, 2004 Heritage Foundation Backgrounder, Paul Kersey argues against an
increase in the minimum wage. He suggests that an increase in the minimum wage would reduce employment
for low-wage workers. Kersey argues that wages in a market economy will rise as demand rises, so there
is no need to artifically increase the wage. He observes that "recent Census data shows that only 15
percent of workers earning within $1.50 of the minimum wage belong to poor families, while 20
percent belong to families whose total earnings exceed $80,000 per year." Thus, the beneficiaries
of a minimum-wage increase are not generally low-income households.
Minimum Wage Neutral
Pro & Con: Does raising the minimum wage help the economy?
Pro-Con Minimum Wage Abolition
Pro Minimum Wage
Minimum Wage Interview
Minimum Wage Articles
|